Thursday, August 23, 2012

Made Everywhere

What does "Made in ______" really mean? On Wednesday, we briefly discussed the idea of gross trade versus value-added trade in the context of the iPhone. The argument was that when the final assembly of the iPhone is imported to the US, its full value (say, about $200) is counted as imports from China to the US in the US trade balance. But really China's value-added is only about $6.50. The rest is made up of components built elsewhere, as well as design, marketing, and financial services that are carried out here, in the US. Scott Lincicome offers a nice graphical example showing how these vertical supply chains work, and where things are typically made from start to finish (I do have a minor quibble with him including the sewing machines in the supply chain, because those aren't really "components", but let's look past that).
The bottom line is that vertical FDI allows firms to specialize production of various stages of production in multiple locations to best exploit the gains from trade and comparative advantage.
We will talk more about the gains from trade and comparative advantage in Chapters 2-4 of the textbook, and more about vertical FDI in Chapters 5 and 7. However, the way that comparative advantage is exploited internally by the firm when it engages in FDI highlights the distributional impacts of trade along the lines of comparative advantage: For the country that is sending capital abroad, the shareholders who own the capital win, as do consumers; the workers who were once employed by that firm domestically lose; yet, the net effect is positive.

Monday, August 20, 2012

How Big Are (or Aren't) the Gains From Trade

One of the things trade economists have traditionally enjoyed doing to hammer home the gains from trade is to cite seemingly outrageous numbers about the positive impacts of trade. For instance, there is this 2003 report from the US International Trade Commission that estimates the net costs from trade restrictions for 1990 to be about $170,000 per job saved (but yes, jobs were saved by protection!). Or, there are these calculations that take a more nuanced approach sector-by-sector:
IndustryAnnual loss to economy from barriers = CostNet employment loss if barrier is removed = jobs "saved"Annual cost PER JOB SAVED
Textile and apparel$ 10.04 billion55,000$ 182,545
Maritime transport$ 2.79 billion2,450$ 1,138,775
Dairy$ 1.01 billion2,083$ 484,878
Motor vehicles$ 710 million3,400$ 208,824
Sugar$ 661 million1,694$ 390,200
Meat$ 185 million100$ 1,850,000
Steel mills$ 162 million1,265$ 128,063
Nonrubber footwear$ 147 million1,316$ 111,702

From McConnell and Brue, 2002
Source: compiled from United States International Trade Commission data released December 1995. Data are for 1993.
New research has called these claims into question, at least somewhat. Jonathan Dingel summarizes some of the new research on trade (which includes contributions by Arkolakis et al., Ossa, and the opinions of Prescott) using more advanced trade models here. Arkolakis, et al. find that the gains from trade in these "new models" is "not much". But, these gains depend on the estimation of elasticity coefficients, which may vary by industry. When these coefficients are estimated separately for different industries, the gains from trade increase by about 6 fold, to somewhere between 24 and 42% of GDP.
Thus, the gains from trade may well be large after all.